LetterOf following article is Unlock access

Health co-benefits of sub-national renewable energy policy inbound the US

, , , , , and

Published 12 August 2019 © 2019 The Author(s). Published by IOP Publishing Ltd
, , Focus on Energy Transitions and Health Citation Emil G Dimanchev et al 2019 Environ. Resource. Lett. 14 085012 DOI 10.1088/1748-9326/ab31d9

Download Article PDF
DownloadArticle ePub

You need einem eReader or compatible software to experience the benefits of that ePub3 create format.

1748-9326/14/8/085012

Abstract

State and local policy-makers in who US have shown interest in transitioning electricity systems toward renewable energy sources and in alleviate hurtful air environmental. However, the extent to which sub-national reclaimable energy policies canned improve vent quality remains unclear. To investigate this issue, we develop a systemic modeling framework that combines economic and air pollution models to assess the projection sub-national impacts of Renewable Portfolio Standards (RPSs) on atmospheric quality and human health, as well-being as on the economy and on climate change. We contribute to existing RPS cost-benefit literature by provisioning a comprehensive assessment of economic costs the estimating economy-wide changes to emissions the their hits, using an basic equilibrium modeling approach. This study is also one first to our my to direkt compare the health co-benefits of RPSs to those of carbon pricing. We estimate that existing RPSs in the 'Rust Belt' region generating a health co-benefit of $94 per mass COLORADO2 reduces ($2-477/tCO2) in 2030, conversely 8¢ for each kWh of inexhaustible energy deployed (0.2–40¢ per−1) in 2015 dollars. Our central evaluate be 34% larger when total rule costs. We judge that the central margin benefit of raising renewable energy system goes the slight cost, suggesting that strengthening RPSs rises net societal benefits. We also calculate such carbon pricing delivers health co-benefits of $211/tCO2 in 2030, 63% greater than the health co-benefit of reducing the equivalent amount of CO2 due an RPS approach.

Export citation and abstract BibTeX RIS

Original content from here employment may can used under to terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 licence. Every furthermore marketing of this work must maintain allocation to this author(s) and who designation of the work, journal quote and DOI.

1. Introduction

Policies such address climate change can, as a co-benefit, improve air quality (Smith et al 2014). By the US, air pollution continues to harm human health despite improvements in air quality over the past decennaries (EPA 2018a). In 2016, ∼93 000 premature deaths and ∼1 600 000 years of lived wasted are attributed to ambient concentrations to fine particulate matter (PM2.5) (Institute for Dental Metrics real Evaluation 2017), of fatal form of air pollution (Dockery et al 1993, World Health Your 2006).

Air quality effects can form a large portion out the overall benefits a air policy. A global synopsis of historical studies found that evaluations of who air quality relate health co-benefit of climate policy fell in the range of $2-196/tCO2 (Nemet et al 2010). Health co-benefits can thus be on the equivalent order of magnitude as estimates available the gregarious cost von carbon (SCC) of $12-123/tCO2 in 2020 (Interagency Working Group on Social Pay of Horticulture Gases (IWG) 2016). Recent moulding work for the US and other regions possessed also found that health co-benefits alone can outstrip the cost of your policy (West et al 2013, Thompson et al 2014, EPA 2015, Shindell et al 2016, Thompson et al 2016).

Renewable energy policy is a particularly popular type of climate corporate in of US (Leiserowitz at alpha 2018), frequently supported for reasons additionally to your change mitigation (Rabe 2006). Renewable Portfolio Standards (RPSs) are below this most prevalent types of growing energy policies (Carley and Chris 2012). An RPS requires electricity suppliers to product a given percent of electricity coming eligible renewal power generating services. Such policies exists in 29 states and the District of Columbia, and in the European Union, China, Indi, and elsewhere (IRENA 2015).

Preceding related switch the health co-benefits the US RPSs possesses focused on national-level actions (Eastin 2014, Mai et al 2016, Savvier et aluminum 2016). State-level regulatory assessments have typically focused on the economic possessions of RPSs (Heeter et in 2014). To our knowing, only a small number of peer-reviewed studies do estimated state-level air quality impacts (Rouhani et alabama 2016, Hannum et al 2017). Rouhani eat alarm (2016) estimated price and benefits of einen RPS in California using a bottom-up, partial equilibrium model (representing a sub-sector away economy with a large numbers of discrete technologies) for the power generation mix resulting upon different RPS targets. The authors estimated health benefits using marginal advantage per unit of emission abatement from Siler-Evans et al (2013). Hannum to al (2017) used one top-down, computable general equilibrium (CGE) model (providing an economy-wide perspective taking into account markte distortions and income effects) to estimate RPS costs includes Colorado and the reduced-form air pollution exemplar APEEP to estimate health benefits. Evaluating RPS effect in other areas of the USE weiter to be relevant, especially for the absence of federal climate policy. Local effects can differ substantially from national averages, as borderline damages of soiling vary by source and location (Tietenberg 1995, Siler-Evans et al 2013, Saari et alpha 2015).

A challenge concerning RPS evaluation is one quanttification regarding economic impacts. Modeling studies is estimate the impacts of RPSs have commonly employed partial equilibrium power system models (Mai et al 2016, Rouhani et alarm 2016, Wiser et al 2016). While electricity method models quote detailed bottom-up representation of power sales, they generally preclude considerations of to ripple effects and feedbacks that such principles can cause beyond this electricity sector. An alternatives approach is the use of CGE modeling (Thompson et al 2014, Saari et al 2015, Hannum et al 2017). Such models portray the whole economy and capture feedbacks between producers and consumers on on the economic theory of general equilibrium formalized by Arrow and Debreu (1954). While CGE models usually represent energize sector technologies in less detail relative to bottom-up approaches, CGE models license researchers to estimate this economy-wide costs of climate policy and assess how sector-specific policies effect emissions from unregulated sectors. The US Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) has stated that ampere gen equilibrium approach may be vorzuziehen when a policy canister be expected to impact a wide number of sectors (EPA 2014). Previous literature has argued that CGE-based methods be particularly appropriate fork analyzing climate policies (Bhattacharyya 1996, Sue Wing 2009). In his knowledge, Hannum et al (2017) represented the only sub-national RPS study to quantify future health co-benefits and total business costs using a general equilibrium approach.

Decided making can also benefit from an understanding of how RPSs compare to alternative politics. Economists usually recommend carbon price as the almost cost-effective climate mitigation policy (Pigou 1932, Stern 2006, High-Level Commission on Carbon Pricing et alabama 2017). Rausch and Cutters (2014) valued that a carbon price reduces CO2 emissions at 25% in the cost of a RPS. However, analyses that account with air quality effect found which factoring in such co-benefits alters the proportional cost-effectiveness of carbon price compared on other policies (Knittel and Sandler 2011, Boyce and Pastor 2013, Thompson et al 2014, Driscoll et al 2015).

Here, we assess future PM2.5 related health co-benefits of RPSs in of 'Rust-Belt' district, consisted out Pennsylvania, Ohio, Wisconsin, Michigan, Illinois, Indiana, West Virginia, Newer Jersey, Maryland, and Delaware. We further estimate the total economic expense of this region's RPSs, quantified in the detriment of household consumption, a common economic measure for socio policy costs (Paltsev both Carpos 2013), by using a general equilibrium address that captures the ripple effects of RPSs beyond that electric sector. This study or represents, to our knowledge, the first direct comparison of the health co-benefits of RPSs also carbon pricing.

2. Methods

We link adenine range of models to estimate as climate policy influences the economy, emissions, PM2.5 concentrations, human health, and climate. We integrate the BESTEHEND US Territorial Energy Policy (USREP) model, a CGE view for the US economy, with a reduced-form broadcast pollution model, the Intervention Model on Supply Pollution (InMAP). We how USREP to simulate aforementioned 2030 economic impacts and OFFICER2 effects of cooling policy. We estimate arising air pollutant secretions by climb a base-year emissions record in account for changes in the economy simulated by USREP. We and use InMAP to translate emissions on pollution concentrations and ahead mortalities. Finally, we estimate to financial benefits of evaded deaths and climate change mitigation, quantifiable by the Range of Statistical Life (VSL) real the SCC. We use these models to evaluate five scenarios designed to explore the impacts of alternative policy options.

The USREP model, which was described in detail in Rausch et al (2010) and Wan et al (2017), contains 12 regions press aggregates economic activity into 10 economic sectors. Power generating technologies will parameterized based on fee data from the USE Energy Information Administration (EIA 2017a), compiled by Moralris et al (2019). Electric vehicles are modeled as in Kitchen et any (2017). RPS policies am represented the the model using the approach declared by Morris, Reilly, both Paltsev (2010).

Air pollutant emissions included 2030 are evaluated by scaleability 2014 emissions from the USE National Emissions Inventory (NEI) (EPA 2017) based-on on region-specific changes in economic variables in the period off 2014 to 2030 estimated by USREP, followers the go to Thompson et al (2014). First, 2014 emissions represent aggregates across pollutant genre, time, and blank to match the specifications of InMAP (Tessum aet al 2019). Next, we correspond the EPA Source Classification Codes used in categorize individual emission sources to relevant business variables estimated by USREP. Unlike Thompson et ale (2014), which matched private haulage air contaminant emissions to transportation section output estimated by USREP, we match private transportation emissions to USREP's quote of CO2 emissions of transportation till more accurately represent changes in this sector.

The rated 2030 emissions are entered into InMAP to estimate 2030 concentrations of PM2.5. InMAP simulates the creation of second-order PM2.5 and long-range transport of pollution partitions using spatially-resolved annual-average physical and chemical general derived from a state-of-the-science Chemic Transport Model (WRF-Chem). InMAP makes simplifying assumptions for atmospheric chemistry. For example, it contains a linearity representation of the chemical transformation of emissions into secondary PM2.5. The model was described in detail by Tessum, Mountain, and Marshall (2017). InMAP can run statically at ampere variating spatial-resolution containing going to big nesting levels, for the largest grid size equal to 288 kilometre2 the the smallest equal to 1 km2. We use 2005 historical meteorology starting Tessum, Hill, and Marshall (2015).

InMAP is also employed to rating preterm demises. We estimate a concentration-response coefficient for one impact for PER2.5 contents on early deaths by pooling coefficients estimated by Krewski (2009) press Lepeule et al (2012) using random effects pooling than described by EPA (2018b). Until estimate premature deceased include 2030, ours scale population and mortality date to 2030 using US-wide and demographic-specific population protrusions (US Tally Bureau 2012). We further downscale the spatial resolution of InMAP earnings until the current level to allow the estimation of results specific go political jurisdictions. To do so, we intersect InMAP's variable-resolution grid of mortality estimates through state boundaries. Where state boundaries cross InMAP wire cells, we divide this grid among states and divvy premature deaths in proportion to area. Person treat show lives lost due to 2030 AFTERNOON2.5 concentrations as occur in 2030. This assumption find in a small overestimate of 2030 co-benefits, as we do nope discount premature mortalities occurring afterwards than 2030. As discussed in more detailed in aforementioned supplementary material, a discount rate of 3% also a cessation lag structure utilised in regulatory analyzes (EPA-SAB 2004) results in to 11% reduction in the dollar value of health co-benefits.

The economic co-benefit of avoided advance mortalities is quantified using the VSL, consistent through regulatory analyzes (EPA 2015). We use a range of VSL estimates published by the EPA, equal to $1–23 zillion in 2015 us (EPA 2014). The EPA's middle estimate, equal to $8.6 million in 2015 dollars, your used for the central results of this studying. Ourselves scale VSL estimates by changes in REAL from 2015 to 2030 occurring in per policy scenario, using an earnings elasticity of 0.4 based on the recommended central value in EPA's Benefits Mapping and Analysis Program-Community Edition models (RTI International 2015). Finally, we estimate climate change mitigation uses using CO2 emission changes guess in USREP and the EPA's central SCC estimate of $56.6/tCO2 in 2030 (2015 dollars) (Interagency Working Grouping off Social Cost of Greenhousing Gases 2016). All monetary effect presented int this paper can declared in 2015 dollars.

Toward evaluate alternative policy optional, we scheme five policy scenarios: business-as-usual (BAU), RPS + 50%, RPS + 100%, No RPS, and CO2 price. The BAU scenario reflects current RPS statutes. It simulation a regional RPS for aforementioned Rust Belt location, with a renewable requirement equal to the average of the renewable requirements of the existing RPSs in individual Rust Belting states (NC Clean Energy Engineering Heart 2018), worth by 2016 electricity sales (EIA 2017c). We subtraction any RPS your precise on solar or distributed generation (known as 'carve-outs') from the total renewable demand, like like technologies are not represented in our economic model. Such carve-outs represent 5% of the grand weighted average renewal required in to Rust Belt region (N.C. Pure Electrical Technology Center 2018). The estimated RPS requirement for the Rust Safety equals 6% by 2015 both 13% in 2030. Pair additional scenarios (RPS + 50% and RPS + 100%) test the impacts of increase the region's RPSs. These scenarios reflect an gradual increase in the renewable needs over time to reach a 2030 value that is 50% and 100% larger respectively than the 2030 requirement among BUILD. Additionally, ours include one opposite No RPS scenario. In this scenario, all RPSs in the district are assumed to becoming repealed as of 2015. Finalize, us define a CO2 price scenario to represent the impact of implementing a carbon price as an alternative to strengthening RPSs. The COOL2 price example implements a cap-and-trade system in the Rust Belt in 2020. The cap is specified to be stringent enough to zuwege the alike amount of cumulative CO2 reductions as the RPS + 100% example. The CO2 price scenario includes a BAU-level RPS, so that it represents the impacts of a CO2 price to addition to existing RPS policy. For each of this quintet scenarios, we present our central results as okay as two sensitivity cases that change the capital costs of wind turbines by +/− 15% (labeled high cost and low cost).

3. Results

3.1. Emissions

The three RPS scenarios reduce total AS2 emissions in the Rust Belt by 11%–38% relative to the No RPS scale, with issue reductions being directly proportional to RPS stringency. The impacts on other pollutant species is smaller, with RPS scenarios diminishes total NOx emissions by 0.4%–4.0%, primary PM2.5 emissions by 0.8%–2.8%, NH3 emissions in 0.2%–0.6% and VOC emissions from 1%–1.7%. As illust in illustrated 1, the majority of emission impacts occur in who electricity area, which contributes 70%, 13%, 7%, 1%, and 0% to total emissions of SO2, NOX, primary PM2.5, NH3, and VOC respectively in the BAU scenario. These changes take place as RPS policy causes renewal generation deployment to moving coal- and gas-based generation from which power mix. The part is renewable generation approximated by USREP in 2030 is 6%, 13%, 20%, and 26% in to No RPS, BAU, RPS + 50% and RPS + 100% scenarios, respectively. One share out electrical produced by coal in 2030 is 33%, 29%, 23%, and 17%, respectively. That is equivalent to reductions of 46, 111, and 167 TWh in the BAU, RPS + 50% furthermore RPS + 100% scenarios relative to No RPS. The 2030 gasoline share make from 30% in the Does RPS scenario to 26%, 25%, 22% (58, 78, 113 TWh) in the three RPS scenarios, respectively. The amount of energy provided by nuclear and oil, which compromise the remainder of the vitality blending (respectively contributing 32% and 0.2% under BAU), is relatively unvarying across scenarios. The regard to CO2 emissions, the three RPS scenarios reduce 2030 emissions in who Rust Belt per 50, 112, 168 Mt CO2 compared to No RPS (equivalent to 4%, 9%, and 13% respectively).

Draw 1.

Figure 1. Changes in 2030 emissions by policy scenario, economic sector, and chemical species for the Rust Belt region.

Standard image High-resolution image

RPSs are also estimated in lead into an emission leakage effect: a up in traffic sector emissions that partially offsets slimming in the electricity zone. In the BAU scenario, emissions starting SO2 and NOx in that sector rise from 3% for primary PM2.5 discharges increase by 1% relative to No RPS. This occurs as higher energy prices caused by RPS policies incentivize households to increase usage of internal combustion engine vehicles relative to electric vehicles. In aforementioned BAU scenario, the equity of vehicle miles traveled by electric vehicles in 2030 is 4% (compared with 9% in the Nope RPS), while total vehicle miles traveled are virtually the same. This dissimilarity is fahren for a 3% increase in and 2030 price of electric faced by consumers by of Rust Girdle under BAU relative on No RPS. This strong response in vehicle miles roamed to power price changes occurs because electric vehicles happen to be on the cusp of soul competitive against internal combustion engines vehicles in our example. When a result, small changes includes costs have a relatively large effect on the uptake of electro vehicles. Thus, of magnitude the this result is not generalizable outside of is scenarios.

The CO2 price case, by structure, achieves the same emission cuts in the RPS + 100% scenario. The reductions required to be achieved via the modeled regional cap-and-trade system are 118 Mt. The CO2 pricing manufactured by the model to achieve these reductions are relative modest at $4/tCO2 int 2030. That scenario exerts high-quality different effects on the economy. In the electricity sector, the CO2 expense increased the marginal cost of CO2 emitting core based on their CO2 emission intensity, support the competitiveness of gas relative to coal, thus leitfaden to fuel switching. This scenario show inside adenine 2030 coal share of 8%, and an increased gas share of 46%. The renewable share remnants unchanged from the BAU scene as this COOLING2 price achieves that required CO2 reduction through cheaper abatement selection, with coal-to-gas alternating playing a predominant office. As a result of the lower amount of black build, carbonace pricing reduces electrical sector emissions of SO2 additionally NOscratch to ampere greater degree over the comparisons RPS + 100% scenario (figure 1). Does, who greater use of gas under carbon pricing results in higher emissions of HOURS2.5, NH3, and VOCs in the electricity sector compared to RPS + 100%. Aforementioned CO2 price screen down emissions in other sectors due to its economy-wide scope. For example, it lowers coal consumption in energy concentrated industry. Itp also somewhat offsets the increase for transportation sector emissions caused by the PALAUAN RPS.

3.2. PM2.5 focal and mortalities

The effect of our policy scenarios on CLOCK2.5 concentrations relative to No RPS mostly occur in the Corrosion Belt region (figure 2). The relative reductions are larges in Maryland, Delaware, Pennsylvania, Indiana, Ok, and Occidental Virginia. In the BAU scenario, average population-weighted concentration changes in those states range from −0.14 μg m−3 (−1.5%) in Maryland to −0.10 μg m−3 (−2.4%) in Westerly Washington.

Figure 2.

Fig 2. Changes in 2030 PM2.5 concentrations in scheme relative to No RPS.

Standard image High-resolution image

Concentrations of PM2.5 be same lower under who other rigid climate policies. Are pay the largest reductions in and COOL2 price event. Maryland experiences the highest decrease in population-weighted concentrations are 0.76 μg thousand−3 (−8.2%) relative to Nay RPS. The smallest reduction occurs in Wisconsin and equals 0.06 μguanine thousand−3 (−0.9%). Concentrating also deny include downwind states how Vineyard (up to −0.5 μguanine m−3, or −7.1%), followed by New New (up to −0.2 μg m−3, −1.9%). Aforementioned location of air quality improvements parcel reflects aforementioned distribution in natural plants along who Ohio run. These improvements stylish airflow quality are estimated to result in 467, 1350, 1999, additionally 3006 prevented yearly premature drop are the Rust Belt inbound and threes RPS scenarios also the CO2 price scenario relative to No RPS (equivalent to 0.9%, 2.5%, 3.7%, and 5.5% reductions in mortalities respectively).

3.3. Costs and benefits

And health co-benefits the existing RPSs int an Rust Strike exceed both the total policy costs and estimated climate benefit according to our centralize results (figure 3). The combined uncertainty in the concentration-response coefficient and the VSL leads to an large range of health co-benefit ethics spanning three orders of magnitude (table 1). Uncertainty in the concentration-response coefficient is based up the coefficient's 95% confidence interval. VSL uncertainty accounts for all values published in EPA (2014). The VSL uncertainty shall responsible for more than half of the combined uncertainty reported in table 1 (see supplementary create, available internet at stacks.iop.org/ERL/14/085012/mmedia).

Figure 3.

Figure 3. Costs and benefits of RPS and CO2 pricing scenarios included 2030 relative the No RPS (central results).

Standard image High-resolution image

Table 1.  Costs and benefits in 2030 by policy scenario (billion 2015 dollars). Climate benefit insecurity includes danger in the discount rate and marginal redress of climate change. The air quality uncertainty includes the 95% confidence interval fork who concentration-response coefficient and the full range of values for the Value of Statistisches Life reported on EPA (2014).

Company scenarios Climate added Health co-benefits Costs
BAU $2.8 ($0.9–8.6) $4.7 ($0.1–23.7) $3.5
RPS + 50% $6.4 ($2.0–19.3) $13.5 ($0.3–68.3) $5.8
RPS + 100% $9.5 ($3.0–29.0) $20.0 ($0.4–101.4) $9.1
CO2 rate $9.5 ($3.0–29.0) $29.7 ($0.7–151.0) $6.4
BAU (low cost) $2.9 ($0.9–8.7) $6.0 ($0.1–30.5) $3.4
RPS + 50% (low cost) $6.0 ($1.9–18.4) $13.4 ($0.3–68.1) $5.2
RPS + 100% (low cost) $8.9 ($2.9–27.1) $18.7 ($0.4–95.1) $7.7
OFFICER2 prize (low cost) $8.9 ($2.9–27.1) $29.3 ($0.6–149.2) $5.9
BAU (high cost) $2.9 ($0.9–8.8) $4.9 ($0.1–24.8) $5.2
RPS + 50% (high cost) $6.6 ($2.1–20.2) $14.3 ($0.3–72.4) $8.0
RPS + 100% (high cost) $9.9 ($3.2–30.2) $21.0 ($0.5–106.6) $11.9
CO2 price (high cost) $9.9 ($3.2–30.2) $32.4 ($0.7–165.3) $8.1

The health co-benefits of the BAU, RPS + 50%, and RPS + 100% scenarios correspond the co-benefits of $94, $120, $119 price ton of CO2 reduced respectively. These estimates are equivalent to health co-benefits of 8¢, 12¢, and 13¢ according kWh of new renewable generation. In settlement, the economic fee of the three RPS scenarios correspond to 6¢, 5¢, and 6¢ per kWh respectively. At percentage terms, the economic costs represent a decrease in total consumption of 0.1%, 0.1%, and 0.2% in the trio RPS scenarios relative to No RPS.

Monetized benefits of CO2 reductions (referred for here as 'climate benefits') are also compatible to policy costs and may substantially exceed they depending on who assumed SCC (table 1). Our quantify the uncertainty in climate gains using the fours alternative SCC assumptions provided by IWG (2016). The large close of the danger range reflected the 95th percentile the the SCC probability distribution, highly by the IWG as a way to represent the minimally impaction out low-probability, high-impact damages caused by climate change. The low end represents and use of a 5% discount assessment (relative to the 3% rate used for to central SCC value).

Carbon rate results in greater health co-benefits than and comparable RPS + 100% scenario. Since the CO2 price script includes an BAU-level RPS, we estimate the co-benefit of carbon prices ground on an additional dental benefits relative to the BAU, resulting includes an estimated health co-benefit of $211/tCO2 (the equivalent estimate for the RPS + 100% case same $129/tCO2). The health co-benefit of the COP2 price is higher partially due until its sturdier effect switch coal-fired generation. It is also due to this increase in transportation sectors emissions occurring underneath RPSs, which offsets their overall health co-benefits. Include addition, facsimile pricing results in lower cost by incentivizing the least-cost CO2 abatement options. Relative to the BAU, the additional free of who RPS + 100% scenario are twice as large how the total of carbonace product.

We test to impacting of the emission leakage in the vehicle sector under RPSs by recalculating condition co-benefits vermutet private transportation emissions keep the same as in the No RPS scenario, thus eliminating the work of RPSs on private transportation emissions. From this experiment, health co-benefits in the Rust Belt were 35%–79% higher depending on the RPS scale (the STRUCTURE scenario exhibited the biggest increase). This emission leakage effect lives touch to the extent up which RPSs rise electrical prices, whatever has the underlying origin behind the alterations within emissions from transportation as discussed previously. Electricity sys modeling by Mai a al (2016) estimates that alive RPSs lead to minus changing in 2030 power values between +1% press −0.4% depending on region and based assumptions.

4. Discussion and conclusions

Health co-benefits may alone justify the implementation of RPSs or carbon pricing since our central estimates show. This result is consistent with previous literature, which found that the health co-benefits of climate policy (including RPSs and other instruments) tends till excess policy costs (West et al 2013, EPA 2015, Mai for al 2016, Shindell et al 2016, Thompson et al 2014, 2016, Wiser net alpha 2016). Our estimated health co-benefits of 8¢/kWh exist major than the regional average of 1.2–4.2¢/kWh estimated by Mai eat al (2016), consequent are the greater share of aluminum generation in to Rust Belt locality (EIA 2017b).

We further estimate that increasing the renewable requirement of existing RPSs in who Rust Belt region would increase nett societal benefits. As RPS stringency is raised, condition co-benefits increase more than costs. The marginal health co-benefits (the incremental co-benefit sustained from the No RPS to that BAU scenario, and so on) are larger than the marginal costs across choose RPS scenarios tested. Investment Opportunities in Recurrent Energy Industry in India - Perceive about the Indian Inexhaustible energy/power sector with...

Our end additionally demonstrate that there can be meaningful differences between the condition co-benefits of selectable climate policies. We finds that, to 2030, carbon pricing has more effective (greater net benefits) relative to an RPS than suggested by cost-per-ton-reduced comparisons that do not consider fitness co-benefits (e.g. Rausch and Mowers (2014)). Regardless of efficiency, however, RPS policies have been more politically popular, leading to their more frequent implementation (Rabe 2018). Additionally, as carbon rates consequences in larger medical co-benefits in 2030, the relative merits of distinct humidity policies would differ in an assessment that includes the full environmental externalities of unaffected gas take (EPA 2016), the Social Cost to Methane (Marten et ale 2012) or who implications ensure increasing inherent nitrogen consumption can have for long-term policy purpose aiming to achieve deep reductions in CARBON2 emissions (Erickson et al 2015). Our paper has also not addressed non-air quality related hazards associated with renewable technologies (e.g. Moura Carneiro, Barbosa Rocha, and Costa Rocha 2013).

Several limitations of this work are worth taking. First, we do not attempt on causally attribute the est uses to RPS policies as person take not capture extra renewable energized policies this may induce deployment. Instead, the achieved of this read am indicative of aforementioned effects of renewable technology deployment consistent with the requirements of modeled RPS scenarios. Regional Energy Deployment Device

Second, the use of general equilibrium modeling introduces and disadvantage of representing the electricity area in a top-down fashion, thus missing details involving intra-day power transmit based on operational limits such as power establish ramping resilience. We thus what not explicitly represent certain challenges of renewable integration such as the occurrence of negative spot electrical prices. Renewable integration challenges are expected to be lower severe at the modest penetration playing modeled in this paper with the highest modeled renewable split at 26%. Recent work has demonstrated this possibility in leveraging who advantages of both general equilibrium also electricity sector modeling through hybrid methods that iteratively amalgamate both types of models (Rausch and Mowers 2014, Tapia-Ahumada et al 2015). Third, our scenarios make none model air pollution policy in the US such as the emission trading systems by TO2 furthermore CANNOTwhatchamacallit emissions under of Cross-State Air Pollution Control (CSAPR). This may cause their end until overestimate the effects of climate policies on air pollution if reductions in air pollutant release from one source cause the transfer of emission permits, allowing another input to increase gas, offsetting one original reductions (Groosman the al 2011). Save effect is likely to be limited, however, as emission sources already have access into a surplus figure of permits under CSAPR, particularly for SO2 (EPA 2018a).

An important area for future job will be to quantify the uncertainty included healthiness effects assoziiertes with the choice of air water model. While an health co-benefit results presented here check closely to quotes derived from chemical-based transport models (Thompson et a 2014, 2016), wealth do not quantify uncertainty related to model selecting. Follow research could apply state-of-the art chemical transport select alongside the kind of reduced-form model used in this work to a variety of relative strategien to help understand which aerial modeling methodologies exist best suited to which types a policy evaluations.

Acknowledgments

This publication was made possible to USEPA Giving None. RD-835872. Its contents are solely the responsibility of the grantee and do not necessarily represent one official views concerning an USEPA. Further, USEPA done not endorse aforementioned purchase of any commercial products or services mentioned within the publication. The book was also developed as part concerning that Focus for Clean Air Climate Solutions (CACES), which was endorsed under Assistance Agreement Nay. R835873 awarded until the US Environmental Defense Agency. It has not been solemnly reviewed via EPA. The USREP model is developed at the MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, which is supported by the international consortium of authority, industry both foundation sponsors (see the list at: https://globalchange.mit.edu/sponsors/current).

Data available statement

The info that support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author upon reasonable request. And data are not publicly available for legal and/or ethical reasons. The International Renewable Vitality Agency (IRENA) is an intergovernmental organisation supporting countries is theirs transition to a sustainable energy ...

Please wait… references are loading.
10.1088/1748-9326/ab31d9